Commonwealth of Australia Explanatory Memoranda

[Index] [Search] [Download] [Bill] [Help]


MINERALS RESOURCE RENT TAX (CONSEQUENTIAL AMENDMENTS AND TRANSITIONAL PROVISIONS) BILL 2011

                              2010-2011



    THE PARLIAMENT OF THE COMMONWEALTH OF AUSTRALIA




                               SENATE




            MINERALS RESOURCE RENT TAX BILL 2011
MINERALS RESOURCE RENT TAX (CONSEQUENTIAL AMENDMENTS AND
             TRANSITIONAL PROVISIONS) BILL 2011
 MINERALS RESOURCE RENT TAX (IMPOSITION-CUSTOMS) BILL 2011
   MINERALS RESOURCE RENT TAX (IMPOSITION-EXCISE) BILL 2011
 MINERALS RESOURCE RENT TAX (IMPOSITION-GENERAL) BILL 2011




             REVISED EXPLANATORY MEMORANDUM




                    (Circulated by the authority of the
      Deputy Prime Minister and Treasurer, the Hon Wayne Swan MP)



THIS MEMORANDUM TAKES ACCOUNT OF AMENDMENTS MADE BY THE
     HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES TO THE BILL AS INTRODUCED


Table of contents Glossary .................................................................................................. 1 General outline and financial impact ....................................................... 3 Chapter 1 Charging for Australia's non-renewable resources ...................................................................... 5 Chapter 2 Overview of the Minerals Resource Rent Tax ............. 11 Chapter 3 Core rules .................................................................... 27 Chapter 4 Mining revenue ............................................................ 45 Chapter 5 Mining expenditure ...................................................... 73 Chapter 6 Allowances................................................................... 95 Chapter 7 Starting base allowances ........................................... 119 Chapter 8 Small miners .............................................................. 145 Chapter 9 Combining mining project interests ............................ 151 Chapter 10 Transfers and splits of mining and pre-mining project interests......................................................... 183 Chapter 11 Winding down and ending of mining and pre- mining project interests ............................................. 213 Chapter 12 Pre-mining project interests ....................................... 235 Chapter 13 Adjustments ............................................................... 241


Chapter 14 Valuations .................................................................. 257 Chapter 15 Accounting for the MRRT .......................................... 279 Chapter 16 Entities ....................................................................... 301 Chapter 17 Integrity measures ..................................................... 317 Chapter 18 Administration of the MRRT ....................................... 337 Chapter 19 Miscellaneous consequential amendments ............... 387 Index ................................................................................................... 391


Glossary The following abbreviations and acronyms are used throughout this combined explanatory memorandum. Abbreviation Definition AFTS Review Australia's Future Tax System Review APA Advance Pricing Agreement ASX Australian Securities Exchange ATO Australian Taxation Office CGT capital gains tax Commissioner Commissioner of Taxation CPI consumer price index GST goods and services tax GST Act A New Tax System (Goods and Services Tax ) Act 1999 ITAA 1936 Income Tax Assessment Act 1936 ITAA 1997 Income Tax Assessment Act 1997 LTBR long term bond rate LTBR + 7 per cent long term bond rate plus 7 per cent MRRT Minerals Resource Rent Tax MRRT (CA&TP) Bill Minerals Resource Rent Tax (Consequential Amendments and Transitional Provisions) Bill 2011 MRRT Bill Minerals Resource Rent Tax Bill 2011 MRRT customs imposition Minerals Resource Rent Tax Bill (Imposition-Customs) Bill 2011 MRRT excise imposition Bill Minerals Resource Rent Tax (Imposition-Excise) Bill 2011 MRRT general imposition Bill Minerals Resource Rent Tax (Imposition-General) Bill 2011 OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development 1


Minerals Resource Rent Tax Abbreviation Definition OECD Guidelines OECD Transfer Pricing Guidelines for Multinational Enterprises and Tax Administrations PAYG pay as you go PRRT Petroleum Resource Rent Tax TAA 1953 Taxation Administration Act 1953 2


General outline and financial impact Minerals Resource Rent Tax The Minerals Resource Rent Tax (MRRT) is a tax on the economic rents miners make from the taxable resources (iron ore, coal and some gases) after they are extracted from the ground but before they undergo any significant processing or value add. `Economic rent' is the return in excess of what is needed to attract and retain factors of production in the production process. The MRRT is a project-based tax, so a liability is worked out separately for each project the miner has at the end of each MRRT year. The miner's liability for that year is the sum of those project liabilities. The tax is imposed on a miner's mining profit, less its MRRT allowances, at a rate of 22.5 per cent (that is, at a nominal rate of 30 per cent, less a one-quarter extraction allowance to recognise the miner's employment of specialist skills). A project's mining profit is its mining revenue less its mining expenditure. If the expenditure exceeds the revenue, the project has a mining loss. Mining revenue is, in general, the part of what the miner sells its taxable resources for that is attributable to the resources in the condition and location they were in just after extraction (the `valuation point'). Mining revenue also includes recoupments of some amounts that have previously been allowed as mining expenditure. Mining expenditure is the cost a miner incurs in bringing the taxable resources to the valuation point. Mining allowances reduce each project's mining profit. The most significant of the allowances is for mining royalties the miner pays to the States and Territories. It ensures that the royalties and the MRRT do not double tax the mining profit. In the early years of the MRRT, the project's starting base provides another important allowance. The starting base is an amount to recognise the value of investments the miner has made before the MRRT. Other allowances include losses the project made in earlier years and losses transferred from the miner's other projects (or from the projects of some associated entities). 3


Minerals Resource Rent Tax If a miner's total mining profit from all its projects comes to less than $75 million in a year, there is a low profit offset that reduces the miner's liability for MRRT to nil. The offset phases out for mining profits totalling more than $75 million. Date of effect: The MRRT applies from 1 July 2012. Proposal announced: The MRRT was announced in the Treasurer's Media Release No. 055 of 2 July 2010. Financial impact: The MRRT will have these revenue implications: 2011-12 2012-13 2013-14 2014-15 Nil $3,700m $4,000m $3,400m Compliance cost impact: This measure is expected to impose significant compliance costs on taxpayers in the iron ore and coal sectors (approximately 320 taxpayers). In the first year of the MRRT's operation, taxpayers will need to value their starting base and modify their accounting procedures. Ongoing compliance costs will reduce over the medium to long term. 4


Chapter 1 Charging for Australia's non-renewable resources Outline of chapter 1.1 This chapter explains the rationale for charging for Australia's non-renewable resources. Australia's non-renewable resources 1.2 Australia is naturally endowed with a large, high quality non-renewable resource base. 1.3 Non-renewable resources are stocks of minerals and petroleum that are exhaustible and depletable. 1.4 The majority of Australia's non-renewable resources are publicly owned. The rights to these non-renewable resources are vested in the Crown. Non-renewable resources and taxation 1.5 It is the characteristic of non-renewability that allows exploitation of these resources to generate economic rent or above normal profit. Economic rent can generally be taxed without distorting the decisions of investors if the tax is well designed. 1.6 There are two main types of resource taxes: royalties and resource rent taxes. Royalties 1.7 In Australia, State and Territory governments typically tax non-renewable resources by applying a royalty to production. Royalties are generally applied on the basis of volume or value and do not take into account how profitable a mining operation is. 5


Minerals Resource Rent Tax 1.8 Royalties therefore may only recover a portion of mining rents when mining profits are high, but will also tax mining operations where no economic rent is present, such as when profits are low. Resource rent taxes 1.9 Resource rent taxes are profit-based, cash flow, taxes. They differ from most royalties in that they take into account the profitability of a mining operation. A resource rent tax collects a percentage of the resource project's economic rent. 1.10 One form of resource rent tax is the Brown tax, invented by Cary Brown in 1948. A Brown tax is a pure cash flow tax levied (at a constant percentage) on the difference between revenue and expenditure. (i) When there is a positive cash flow, the government taxes that positive cash flow. When there is a negative cash flow, typically at the investment phase, the government provides an immediate refund at the tax value. (ii) The tax rate determines the portion of economic rent that the government collects, and the value of the refund that they provide. 1.11 Under a Brown tax, the government is effectively sharing in the profits and costs of the mining project in proportion to the tax rate. 1.12 However, the Brown tax model is difficult to implement because of the immediate nature of the refund. So governments typically rely on other models of resource rent taxes that mimic the effect of the Brown tax. 1.13 The Garnaut -- Clunies-Ross resource rent tax is a resource rent tax model that attempts to replicate the effects of a Brown tax. It is named after the Australian economists Ross Garnaut and Anthony Clunies-Ross. The Garnaut -- Clunies-Ross resource rent tax is levied on the positive cash flows, or profits, of a project, but there is no refund when the cash flow is negative or the taxpayer is making a loss. Instead, losses are carried forward and `uplifted' by an interest rate, so that they can be used as a deduction against positive cash flows in later years. 1.14 The uplift rate preserves the value of the taxpayer's losses because they do not get an immediate refund for the tax value of the government's contribution to the mining project. The uplift rate also includes a premium to compensate for the risk that the taxpayer may never get to use its losses. 6


Charging for Australia's non-renewable resources 1.15 The Petroleum Resource Rent Tax (PRRT) is an example of a Garnaut -- Clunies-Ross resource rent tax. Background to the Minerals Resource Rent Tax 1.16 The Minerals Resource Rent Tax (MRRT) has its origins in the recommendations of the Australia's Future Tax System (AFTS) Review. 1.17 The AFTS Review found that the royalty regimes applied by the States and Territories were among the most distorting taxes in the Federation. In addition, royalty regimes are not particularly flexible. 1.18 As a consequence of being distorting and relatively inflexible, royalties tend to be set at rates low enough for the mining industry to continue to operate in periods of low to average commodity prices. However, this means that royalties will often fail to provide an adequate return to the community when commodity prices are high. 1.19 The company tax is a profits-based tax, which generally applies to incorporated businesses and will tend to raise more revenue from mining operations when profits are high. However, the AFTS Review found that there would be benefits to the economy more broadly through lowering the company tax rate to assist in attracting internationally mobile capital investment. 1.20 The AFTS Review concluded that a lower company tax rate was desirable for Australia but only if a specific profits-based tax was extended to mining operations to ensure a sufficient return to the community in periods of high commodity prices. 1.21 In response to the AFTS review, the Government decided that, from 1 July 2012, the MRRT would apply to profits from coal and iron ore operations, while the PRRT would be extended to all offshore and onshore gas and oil projects, including coal-seam methane. These commodities account for the bulk of Australia's mineral wealth. 1.22 The detailed design of the MRRT is based on the recommendations of the Policy Transition Group. The Policy Transition Group was chaired by Don Argus AC and the Hon Martin Ferguson AM MP, Minister for Resources, Energy and Tourism. The Policy Transition Group consulted extensively across Australia on the new resource tax arrangements and reported to the Government in December 2010. 7


Minerals Resource Rent Tax The Minerals Resource Rent Tax 1.23 The MRRT is a type of resource rent tax based on the Garnaut -- Clunies-Ross model. 1.24 Under the MRRT, the government taxes positive cash flows, or mining profits, and allows taxpayers to carry forward and uplift losses with interest for use in later years. 1.25 As the MRRT taxes profits from minerals that are commonly subject to State and Territory royalties, it provides a credit for royalties. 1.26 The tax base for the MRRT is confined to net profits at the valuation point. The valuation point is the point in the mining production chain that separates upstream and downstream operations. 1.27 As the MRRT is intended to apply only to upstream profits, it is a tax on a narrow portion of mining profits unlike, for example, the income tax, which seeks to tax all sources of income comprehensively. 1.28 The MRRT is a tax on realised profits. As the proceeds from the sale of a resource are typically realised downstream of the valuation point, the MRRT requires taxpayers to determine the amount of those proceeds that are reasonably attributable to the resource and upstream operations for tax purposes. The tax is not intended to tax the value added in downstream activities. 1.29 To calculate the MRRT profit at the valuation point, the sales proceeds are reduced by an amount that recognises the arm's length value of the downstream operations using the most appropriate and reliable method. Allowable upstream capital and operating expenditure is then directly and immediately deducted, along with royalty credits, carry forward losses, starting base depreciation, starting base losses and losses transferred from other projects. 1.30 If losses and royalty credits cannot be used within an MRRT year, they are transferred where possible, or carried forward to later years with the relevant uplift rate applied. 1.31 Through providing effective deductions for all allowable capital and operating expenditure, with an uplift of carry forward losses, the tax base for the MRRT approximates a Brown tax on the profit attributable to the resource in the state it was in at the valuation point. 1.32 As the sources of mining rents are difficult to identify separately in practice, the MRRT aims to strike an appropriate balance between recovering a sufficient return to the community for the profits attributable 8


Charging for Australia's non-renewable resources to the underlying resource rent at the valuation point, and recognising that some mining expertise and capital may also be taxed in a process which has regard to realised profits and their equivalents. This balance is achieved through the combined effect of the features of the tax, including the tax rate, the extraction factor, the valuation point, the interest allowance (uplift) and the scope of assessable revenues and allowable deductions. 1.33 An overview of the operation of the MRRT is provided in Chapter 2. 9


Chapter 2 Overview of the Minerals Resource Rent Tax Outline of chapter 2.1 This chapter is an overview of the Minerals Resource Rent Tax (MRRT). It outlines the resources that are subject to MRRT and explains the basic operation of the MRRT. Overview of the MRRT What resources are covered? 2.2 Australia is endowed with some of the world's largest and most valuable deposits of iron ore and coal. These bulk commodities make up a large proportion of Australia's mine production and mineral exports. 2.3 The MRRT applies to certain profits from iron ore and coal extracted in Australia. It also applies to profits from gas extracted as a necessary incident of coal mining and gas produced by the in situ combustion of coal. These non-renewable resources are called `taxable resources'. 2.4 Where profits are made from the sale of taxable resources, or would have been made if the resources had been sold instead of being exported or used, MRRT may be payable. Basic operation of the MRRT 2.5 This section explains the operation of the MRRT and how it applies to three different cases. The first case, the `vanilla' case, examines how the MRRT operates for a project that was not in existence before the announcement of the MRRT. 2.6 The second case examines how the MRRT operates for projects that are transitioning into the MRRT (that is, for projects that were already invested in when the MRRT was announced). It explains how the MRRT recognises those existing investments. 11


Minerals Resource Rent Tax 2.7 The third case shows how the MRRT operates for miners with multiple projects. It introduces the concepts of pre-mining losses and transferring mining losses and pre-mining losses between projects owned by the miner. It also explains the process of `uplifting' unused amounts. The `vanilla' case 2.8 The key purpose of the MRRT is to tax the economic rents from non-renewable resources after they have been extracted from the ground but before they have undergone any significant processing or value-add. Generally, the profit attributed to the resource at this point represents the value of the resource to the Australian community. Where the taxable resource is improved through beneficiation processes, such as crushing, washing, sorting, separating and refining, the value added is attributable to the miner. Mining project interests 2.9 The mining project interest provides the basic unit for taxing the non-renewable resource. The main kind of mining project interest is an entitlement to share in the output of a mining venture carried on to extract taxable resources and produce a resource commodity (which could be the taxable resource or something produced from the taxable resource). It must relate to at least one production right. A production right is a right, under an Australian law, that authorises its holder to extract the resources from a particular area (called a `project area'). Mining profit or loss 2.10 Once a mining project interest has been identified, the mining profit for the interest for the year has to be determined. The mining profit is the mining project interest's mining revenue for the year less its mining expenditure. If the mining expenditure exceeds the mining revenue, the excess is a mining loss. Mining revenue 2.11 The main type of mining revenue a mining project interest can have comes from selling, exporting or using taxable resources (or things produced from taxable resources) extracted from the project area. The proceeds are mining revenue to the extent they are reasonably attributable to the taxable resources at a particular point in the production chain (called the `valuation point'). 2.12 Under the MRRT, the valuation point is typically just before the taxable resource leaves the run-of-mine stockpile (also called the ROM stockpile or ROM pad). The run-of-mine stockpile is where the resource is stored after extraction ready for the next stage of production. The next 12


Overview of the Minerals Resource Rent Tax unit of production could be transportation but is often some form of processing. However, not all mining operations use a run-of-mine stockpile. Where a project has no run-of-mine stockpile, or it is by-passed for any reason, the valuation point is generally just before the first beneficiation process starts. 2.13 Mining operations that occur before the valuation point are upstream mining operations; those that occur afterwards are downstream mining operations. Diagram 2.1: The valuation point In this diagram, the dashed line represents the valuation point at the run-of-mine stockpile. Upstream and downstream mining operations are illustrated. 2.14 The MRRT is a tax on proceeds from selling a taxable resource (or on the proceeds which would have been realised if the resources had been sold instead of exported or sold) but only on that part of those proceeds that is reasonably attributable to the condition and location of the resource when it was at the valuation point. That amount must be attributed using the most appropriate and reliable method having regard to the miner's circumstances, the available information and certain statutory assumptions (to the extent to which they are relevant in applying a particular method). The statutory assumptions are that the downstream operations are carried on by a separate entity who has no interest in the resource and who deals independently with the miner in a competitive market. 2.15 Miners can elect to use a safe harbour method under which the mining revenue amount is worked out by reducing the amount realised from selling the resource (or, the arm's length value of the resource when it is exported or used) by the cost of its downstream mining operations -- being its operating costs, any depreciation and its cost of capital (being its weighted average cost of capital). 2.16 An alternative, and simpler, valuation method is provided for smaller miners and miners who transform resources they mine in an integrated operation, such as steel manufacturing or electricity generation, to work out the mining revenue attributable to their resources. 13


Minerals Resource Rent Tax 2.17 The alternative valuation method is a version of the `netback' method, which starts with a verifiable price and deducts costs to `net back' to the value at an earlier point. Miners who have not elected to use the alternative valuation method may use the netback method to value their taxable resources, but they will have to work out the inputs using the most appropriate method instead of using those prescribed for the alternative valuation method. Mining expenditure 2.18 The MRRT recognises the majority of upstream costs incurred by the miner in extracting the non-renewable resource and getting it to the valuation point. 2.19 Upstream costs are called mining expenditure if they are necessarily incurred by the miner in carrying on the upstream mining operations. Mining expenditure includes costs related to construction of the mining operation, blasting and digging, infrastructure, and capital assets used to transport the non-renewable resource to the valuation point (such as dump trucks and conveyor belts). 2.20 Under the MRRT, upstream capital expenditure is immediately deductible. Unlike income tax, capital assets do not have to be depreciated over their effective lives. 2.21 Some expenditure is specifically excluded from being taken into account as mining expenditure, including financing payments, the costs of acquiring a mining interest, royalty payments, and some tax payments. Allowances 2.22 Miners reduce their mining profit by their MRRT allowances, to arrive at a net amount, which, for convenience, is referred to in this chapter as the MRRT profit. 2.23 In the vanilla case, the relevant allowances are royalty allowances and mining loss allowances. Royalty allowances 2.24 Miners will generally pay royalties to State and Territory Governments. Royalty regimes and rates vary across jurisdictions but are most commonly a charge on the volume or value of the resource, generally at the point of export or sale to a third party. These royalties are often a proxy for the rents available from that resource. 2.25 The miner will be liable to pay some MRRT in addition to royalties when resource rents are sufficiently high. That is, the company 14


Overview of the Minerals Resource Rent Tax will pay the royalty and then also pay MRRT. However, the MRRT recognises this by providing the miner with a deduction, called a royalty allowance. The royalty allowance is `grossed-up', using the MRRT rate, so that it reduces the MRRT liability by the amount of the royalty. 2.26 Where the full royalty credits for the year cannot be applied as a royalty allowance, the unused portion is uplifted and carried forward to be applied in a later year. The uplift rate is the long term bond rate plus 7 per cent (LTBR + 7 per cent). Mining loss allowances 2.27 If a mining project interest has a loss for the year, the loss is uplifted at LTBR + 7 per cent and carried forward to be used in a later year. When it is applied to reduce a mining profit of the mining project 15


Index] [Search] [Download] [Bill] [Help]